This past Thursday was a bit of an odd day for me. In writing my Verdict column, as I was trying to come up with a list of things that Republicans might offer to Democrats as part of "real bargaining" (as opposed to hostage-taking), I noted that "Democrats want Republicans to stop filibustering the President's judicial nominees." Later in the day, when I wrote my Dorf on Law post, I described how the lack of a neutral baseline defining the rules of "true football" made recent complaints about rules changes in the NFL ring hollow.
Several commenters on my DoL post noted immediately that my analysis there could easily apply to Republicans' complaints about the changes that Democrats had passed in the filibuster rules that day. One commenter said that he assumed that I had intended the comparison. I have to admit that I was not doing any such thing. I had, in fact, not even been checking my usual news sites for a couple of days. Even though I knew that the filibuster was suddenly a hot topic again, I did not know about the vote, and I certainly had not read any of the Republicans' specious complaints.
Now that I have caught up on the news, however, I see that the comparison is even more apt than I could ever have planned. My point in Thursday's post was that you can just as easily have football with rules that "favor the defense" as you can with offense-favoring rules, and the only thing that you can say is that the two sets of rules are different. You can assess whether you like the way the game is played under the two sets of rules, applying some external set of criteria, but you cannot say that one game's rules fundamentally differ from some mythical "rules of nature" that supposedly define football.
The over-heated, silly comments that we have been hearing from current and retired NFL defensive players are nothing compared to the Republicans' complaints about Thursday's changes. John McCain called them a "travesty," which amounts to little more than one of his usual temper tantrums. ("I liked the old rules. The new rules are a travesty!") He can complain about losing his power all he likes, but if by travesty he means "travesty of justice," he is simply wrong, because there is no baseline definition of justice that requires the Senate to have a 60-vote requirement (or any other number) to confirm executive and judicial nominees.
The essence of the silliness, however, was captured by faux-moderate Republican Senator Lamar Alexander, whose name appeared on the byline of an op-ed in the Washington Post on Friday. Alexander was at least correct to point out that Democrats have similarly raved about the sanctity of the filibuster in their time, quoting Sen. Carl Levin (who was quoting former Republican Sen. Arthur Vandenberg) as follows: "If a majority of the Senate can change its rules at any time, there are no rules."
Other than the "gotcha" aspect of this line having once been uttered by a Democrat (although Levin himself voted against the changes on Thursday), where is the content here? Beyond the complete lack of a filibuster in the Constitution or any other authoritative source of law, what does it mean to say that there are no rules because the Senate can change the rules at any time? The process of making rules is apparently still set by majority rule. Otherwise, the 52-48 vote would not have changed anything. But that rule is just as arbitrary (albeit appealing to core notions of democracy) than a rule that requires that, say, a procedure cannot be changed until the change has been voted upon three times, with progressively larger numbers of Senators voting for it on each iteration. That fanciful rule, like any other, could be gamed, just as the most recent version of the filibuster procedure had been gamed.
So, yes, the similarities between the complaints about recent NFL rule changes and the Republican outcry about the filibuster changes made the timing of my Thursday post inadvertently apt. Both sets of complaints are based on the fundamental error of claiming that one's preferred set of rules is "right" in some deep sense of an "untilted playing field." This is obviously not to say that any set of rules is as good as any other, but that the goodness or badness of the rules cannot be assessed by some appeal to a Platonic ideal of rules.
It is one thing to listen to people like Ray Lewis and Mike Golic complain about the loss of the good ol' days when they could more easily injure their opponents. Seeing Republican Senators talk about the august nature of the Senate, while insulting the intelligence of anyone listening to their whining, is quite another. Beyond the Republicans' completely situational complaints, however, there is an additional interesting lesson to be learned from last week's events.
As I noted above, my Verdict column offhandedly included a reference to the raft of Republican filibusters of Obama's judicial nominees. (I could also have mentioned their filibusters of his executive-branch nominees, and their filibusters of legislation, the latter of which are still possible under the new rules.) I offered this example in the same generic category as tax increases on the rich, or labor law reforms. The idea was that the Republicans could use the filibuster as one of their bargaining chips. For example, they could say: "I'll agree not to filibuster 10 of your judicial nominations, and I'll also give you a $2-per-hour increase in the minimum wage, a tripling of the budget for Food Stamps, and a reduction in the eligibility age for Medicare to 25, if you'll agree to repeal the ACA, and ... ."
In the context of that column, I was merely expanding on a point that I had made a few weeks ago here on Dorf on Law, which is that negotiating requires giving as well as getting. This is in contrast to the threat not to increase the debt ceiling, and arguably also the threat to shut down the entire government, because the extreme damage from those actions is so different from the consequences of agreeing to the various tradeoffs involved in what used to count as normal legislating. ("You want the capital gains tax rate to go from 15% to 25%, and I want it to go down to 12%. I think things will be worse than necessary if we compromise at 19%, but I don't have the votes to push it lower. Oh well.")
Now consider what the Republicans have inadvertently revealed. The basic objection to Republican hostage-taking regarding the debt ceiling is that there is no legitimate policy interest in refusing to increase the debt ceiling (and thus preventing the country from honoring its commitments), because the normal legislative process will determine the level of debt in the future. This, in turn, means that if Republicans refuse to increase the debt ceiling, and thus risk destroying the financial system and the economy, the President must choose not to negotiate with hostage-takers, because there are legitimate means by which one's debt goals could be reached.
It is true, of course, that people can and do negotiate with hostage-takers all the time. Republicans thus try to meta-frame the argument by saying that the President could negotiate over the debt ceiling (again), so he is the one who would be responsible for any harm that might come to the hostages. That, however, is no different from a kidnapper shooting his victim and then saying, "See what you made me do?!"
When President Obama agreed to negotiate over the debt ceiling in 2011, he did not have to do so, and doing so was quickly seen to have been a grave mistake. Yet he had acted as if negotiating over the debt ceiling was just another normal part of the log-rolling process by which legislation is created.
For the past five years, Senate Democrats had been going along with the idea that it was normal and acceptable to have to garner 60 votes to do anything. Republicans not only threatened to use the filibuster, but they used it repeatedly. Finally, Democrats said, "Hey, we don't have to do this anymore. We've been begging them to do things differently, and we probably would have agreed not to do this if they had allowed even one of Obama's DC Circuit nominees to go through. Time to stop negotiating, because there is nothing stopping us from getting what we want without having to give them anything."
I suspect that the same thing will happen, if the Republicans ultimately carry through on their threats not to increase the debt ceiling. The President will find a way to invoke Buchanan-Dorf, the Republicans will scream about lawlessness, and so on. What we saw last week was a smaller version of that category of political standoffs where one side suddenly realizes that they have been needlessly constraining themselves. While it is always admirable to see partisans refuse to exercise the full extent of their powers (for reasons of comity, public relations, and so on), last week's events are a telling example of what happens when one side overplays its hand.
stop
filibustering the President’s judicial nominees - See more at:
http://verdict.justia.com/2013/11/21/republicans-need-understand-possible-negotiate-without-taking-hostages#sthash.ZJGc2TNC.dpufD
6 comments:
The filibuster issue is an interesting illustration of Game Theory and until last week’s changes, the situation seems like it was a Nash Equilibrium. In a 60 vote requirement scenario, the party in the minority and not in control of the White House could obtain some control of the nomination/confirmation process by blocking confirmations up to maximum point where the majority was threatening to change the rules. At that point a compromise would be reached where some but not all of the appointments were approved. Given that each side knew the strategy of the other side, this was the best outcome they could achieve. Each side had some control over the nomination/confirmation process despite the fact that one side was in the minority.
So preserving this process was the Nash Equilibrium point for both parties, since the minority Senate party and the party in control of the White House changes over time between Democrats and Republicans. But the Equilibrium holds only so far as both parties are willing to play by the rules of the game. The Senate minority, in this case the Republicans changed the rules by blocking appointments beyond the number that would prevent the Senate majority, the Democrats, from changing the rules, and so the ‘game’ has been altered because one side no longer was playing by the ‘rules’, causing the other side to change the rules.
The over-reaction of the Republicans is entirely predictable, they have been kicked out of the old game and thrust into a new game, just as the reaction by the defensive players in the NFL is entirely predictable as the rules for playing their game have changed. Of course, one question is whether or not the Republicans violated the rules (blocking too many appointments) accidentally or by design, the design being to change the confirmation rules so that they favor Republicans when they are in power without the Republicans having to endure the stigma of changing the rules. One would like to think they were that clever, but the evidence that Republicans are clever is sorely lacking.
" we probably would have agreed not to do this if they had allowed even one of Obama's DC Circuit nominees to go through. "
Really?
http://talkingpointsmemo.com/dc/senate-confirms-srinivasan-to-powerful-d-c-circuit-court
TDPE's suggestion that the Republicans set this up so that they would not be the ones to drop The Bomb is an interesting one. Even if it wasn't planned, they certainly will avoid whatever PR hit might have come from their changing the rules. (For what it's worth, I don't think the PR really matters much, nor do I think the Republicans would have cared about bad PR on that issue. But, hey, if someone else will take the hit for you, why not?)
The pointed question from andy grewal calls for a clarification. I should have said "... allowed even one of Obama's three DC Circuit nominees that the Republicans filibustered this Fall to go through." I express no opinion about whether that is a reasonable line to draw. I'm simply saying that the breaking point for Democrats apparently was that all three were filibustered. My breaking point would have come long before that.
Mr. Buchanan and Mr. Grewal raise an interesting point in terms of the Game Theory aspect of this, which is how many nominees would the Republicans have needed to allow a vote on to prevent the rule change. With no basis other than gut feeling I think allowing one nominee to go through would have peeled off enough Democrats to prevent Mr. Reid from having the votes to change the rule. He lost a few Democrats in the actual vote.
If that was the case, then Republicans (assuming they really did not want the rule change) could have paid a very low price in return for being able to block a large number of nominations, which would have been a substantial accomplishment for a party that is a minority in the Senate and does not hold the White House.
Until the recent successful strategy Mr. Obama adopted over the debt ceiling/government shutdown it was pretty clear he had no idea of the principles of Game Theory. But at least he learned, or someone taught him. It seems the Republicans are still clueless.
allowed even one of Obama's three DC Circuit nominees that the Republicans filibustered this Fall to go through." I express no opinion about whether that is a reasonable line to draw. I'm simply saying that the breaking point for Democrats apparently was that all three were filibustered. My breaking point would have come long before that. Fifa 14 Coins
elo boost
Two traveling angels stopped to spend the night in the home fifa 14 coins of a wealthy family. The family was rude and refused to let the angels stay in the mansion's guestroom. Instead the angels cheap fifa 14 coins were given a small space in the cold fifa 14 coins basement.
Post a Comment