Thursday, September 15, 2011

Who Cares About the Evidence?

-- Posted by Neil H. Buchanan

My new Verdict column, published today, confronts the intensifying calls from conservative politicians and their enablers to reduce or eliminate taxes on businesses and the wealthy. Much of the column covers standard distributional analysis. I also discuss the common analytical flaw of focusing only on the effects of taxes on those who pay, while ignoring how the tax revenues are spent.

To put the latter point more bluntly than I did in the column, it is always possible to tell a story about why some tax has -- or could have -- an effect that we might not like (such as creating perverse incentives, reducing some kind of spending or investing, and so on). If we were to limit ourselves to taxes that have no possible behavioral consequence that we might regret, then there would be no acceptable choices. While radical anti-government ideologues might applaud that result during a Republican presidential debate (between cheering for executions, and calling for allowing uninsured coma patients to die), even the watchman state must collect taxes from some source. "This tax might have a bad effect," therefore, is not a serious argument against that tax.

That might seem like an obvious point, and it ought to be. As we know, however, modern politics has become overwhelmed with arguments that ought to embarrass everyone involved. Another obvious point is that evidence ought to matter. From climate change to the Confidence Fairy, however, it is obvious that wishful thinking has replaced assessment of the evidence in too many people's minds.

It is not only the general public and politicians, however, who ignore evidence. A central point in my Verdict column is that there is no convincing empirical support for the claims that taxes (at levels seen in the United States and even Europe) actually harm the economy. A recent news analysis in the NYT quoted a prominent public finance economist as saying that the evidence that capital gains taxes harm economic growth is "murky, at best." In less guarded terms, the economist was saying that we have tried and tried to find the negative effect of capital gains taxes on investment that standard economic theory assures us must be there, but the evidence just will not cooperate. A few studies succeed, but most do not. The same is true, in fact, of other areas of tax analysis as well. Standard economic theory tells us that there is a bad effect, but the evidence is, shall we say, less than clear-cut.

This is significant not just because of the public policy debate, but because of what it says about academic discourse. Even though the "taxes harm growth" hypothesis is supported by murky evidence, at best, tax scholarship and academic discussions typically proceed as if the evidence supported the theory. Why would we do that?

One answer is that responsible academic discussion must include variables that could matter, in order to be complete. Including a variable in an economic model (or even in informal discussions of models) presumes the possibility that the coefficient on any given variable could be zero, in which case there is nothing lost by allowing ex ante for the possibility that the coefficient is theoretically likely to be negative.

As far as it goes, that is a nice explanation. The problem is that it gives us no way to explain why other variables with no empirical significance are never included in the discussion. After decades of empirical failure, we continue to hold out the possibility that certain variables will stop disappointing us. Apparently, we as a group are deeply convinced that taxes must have bad effects, but we simply have not looked hard enough. It also does not explain why so many scholars make policy prescriptions on the basis of the theory and not the evidence.

This phenomenon is hardly limited to taxes. In the 1990's, there was an enormous brouhaha over a famous study of the effects of the minimum wage on low-wage employment. The widely accepted theory was that increases in the minimum wage reduce employment. An innovative study then found that there was no such negative effect, and there might even be a positive one. Perhaps more important as a scientific matter, the authors of the new study also published an article analyzing all previous studies on the subject, finding not only that the evidence was murky, at best, but that the previous studies, when looked at in the aggregate (meta-study), violated a key property of statistical analysis.

The minimum wage story, of course, is now a matter of scientific pride. Even though there are those (even inside academia) who continue to insist that minimum wages harm employment, the combination of new evidence and assessment of old evidence changed the scholarly conversation. The effect of minimum wages is now considered an open, context-specific matter.

Beyond that one outstanding example, however, economic debates often seem to proceed more on the basis of received theoretical wisdom than assessment of the evidence. This is true even when, as in the example above regarding capital gains taxes, the disappointing assessment of the evidence is provided by a member in good standing of the economics tribe.

For example, standard macroeconomic models are nearly always specified to include a negative effect of interest rates on business investment. The theory is that increased borrowing costs will make it more expensive for businesses to buy new capital, which is a simple application of the standard downward-sloping demand curve. The problem is that the evidence in support of that proposition does not even qualify as murky. It is just not there. One of the top macro guys at MIT wrote an assessement of the evdience in the 1980's, in which he noted drily that it takes "more than the usual amount of econometric ingenuity" to "force" an empirical study to show the desired negative relationship. Nothing in the ensuing years would change that overall assessment of the evidence. Again, however, the norm is to talk as if this negative effect is a real-world phenomenon.

In the legal academy, tax scholars also tend to talk as if the evidence relevant to our areas of inquiry is not murky. The typical move is to simply state as a known fact that taxes harm growth, or that they reduce investment, or whatever. Given that legal scholars are allowed (and in many cases encouraged) to be multidisciplinary, and that they do not have to worry about whether they are offending a dearly-held assumption of another academic field, why would they follow economists in failing to notice or acknowledge the lack of empirical support for such important propositions?

My best guess is that, for all the arrogance that legal scholars bring to the table (and we do bring it!), there is an underlying level of professional modesty and doubt that creates a strong tendency to defer to economists on these matters. Although this is true in other fields of law as well, I suspect that it is especially strong in tax law. The academic discourse in tax law is driven by vintage economic theories, and legal scholars in tax, I think, tend to believe that economists really have the answers. This is unfortunate. While it is true that one needs to have a decent grasp of key concepts of public finance economics to understand tax analysis, that is a far cry from saying that the economists have all the answers.

In any event, the academic discourse in tax is truly odd. The evidence about some of the core questions under study should give anyone serious pause about believing the conventional wisdom. Yet economists -- for a combination of reasons -- continue to act as if the conventional wisdom works, while legal scholars too often act as if the economic theory, and not the econometric evidence, is the path to the truth. This is far better than simply ignoring evidence for ideological advantage, as we see among politicians. It is still, however, quite damaging to our understanding of how to improve matters.

8 comments:

CJColucci said...

I used to hear about the disappearing supermarket bag boy as evidence of the effects of minimum wages. For the last several years, virtually all supermarkets I shop at have had bag persons at most check-out aisles. How can this be?
Is it possible that the declining real value of the minimum wage made it economical to hire bag people again? Perhaps things like minimum wages, taxes, and interest rates, which theory tells us "have to" have certain effects actually do, but only at very high levels not likely to be seen in real life?

Paul Scott said...

One of the conflations that has happened that makes little sense to me is the lumping together of "the rich" (individuals) and "businesses."

There ultimately be no empirical evidence to support that increasing taxes on "businesses" reduces job creation, but it is clear that taxes on "business" and "the rich" are not the same thing.

"The rich" don't create jobs at all. They also don't make money from money by staying away from investment. Investment is how the money is made and there is not a reasonable alternative for that class of individual to make the sort of money they are making. Therefor there is not even a good theoretical (much less empirical) reason to avoid a significant increase in the capital gains rate (the main tax paid by "the rich").

Taxes on "business" (which, really, also take too many forms to really be lumped together - but I'll just ignore that for this small reply post) are very different and are more akin to income tax than capital gains taxes. And anyone who pays income taxes knows that those taxes have very real effects on your own spending and investment.

There are reasonable theoretical arguments (many of which, as Neil suggests, may lack empirical support) that taxes on "business" does cause a business to behave differently. There are even reasonable philosophical arguments for eliminating corporate taxation altogether (though these necessarily go along with recognizing, Romney's impassioned pleas not-withstanding, that corporations are not people).

Michael C. Dorf said...

I confess to never having quite understood the standard economic view of the effect of taxes--even in theory. That view says that if someone only gets to keep (1-tax rate)x(gross pay), he will work less hard than if he gets to keep all of his gross pay because he has a greater incentive to work for more money. But this ignores the fact that someone who seeks a certain level of after-tax income will have to work harder to get that same level of after-tax income as tax rates increase. Obviously, at some sufficiently high rate of taxation, we see perverse effects like widespread tax evasion. But below that level, there is a straightforward economic account of how higher taxes could lead to higher productivity.

Paul Scott said...

Well,
I do think - at theoretically (no idea if this turns out true in practice) - you should get some effects even with today's standards.

I know, even at my modest income level, I (or really, my accountant) works hard to classify various forms of income and, being a small business owner, to classify various forms of expense to avoid some tax consequences.

One thing, for example, is that I rent my office space to my business. It is a net zero cash effect, but then the rental income becomes passive income and I do not pay self-employment taxes on the "income." That is a small example from a very small-time business.

I expect larger businesses have all sorts of incentives to minimize the "income" of their highly paid-employs and find a way to convert that to capital gains.

At some level - say a lawyer earning $1M+ annually, I would think that that lawyer would be looking for ways to stop being a lawyer and become an investor so that his income is not taxed at the same rate.

I think those are perverse incentives. Frankly, I think taxing true income at all is a mistake, from a policy position, but I concede out of the box that replacing the income tax with a national VAT and then providing subsidies so that our tax system did not become massively regressive is almost certainly a non-starter, but it would in my mind fix a lot of the problems that come from the perverse incentives that taxing income, at least in theory, provides.

Kobe Bryant said...

seo博客 英文seo
The rich" don't make work at all. They also don't generate income from income by being away from financial commitment decision. Investment is how the income is created and there is not a affordable choice for that training of person to develop the kind of income they are generating. Therefor there is not even a good theoretical (much less empirical) purpose to steer clear of a major improve in the investment capital results pace (the major tax purchased out by "the rich").WOW Gold

Shak Olreal said...

he will work less hard than if he gets to keep all of his gross pay because he has a greater incentive to work for more money. But this ignores the fact that someone who seeks a certain level of after-tax income will have to work harder to get that same level of after-tax income as tax rates increase. Obviously, at some sufficiently high rate of taxation, we see perverse effects like widespread tax evasion. But below that level, there is a straightforward economic account of how higher taxes could lead to higher productivity. Buy Cheap Windows 7 Key
Windows 7 ultimate Key
Windows 7 professional Key
Windows 7 Key

amine lahragui said...


thanks so much for that great blog and thanks also for accepting my links thanks
طريقة عمل الدونات طريقة عمل البان كيك طريقة عمل الكنافة طريقة عمل البسبوسة طريقة عمل الكيك طريقة عمل عجينة البيتزا فوائد القرفه
thanks so much i like very so much your post
فوائد الحلبة فوائد الزنجبيل فوائد الرمان فوائد زيت السمسم علاج البواسير فوائد البصل فوائد اليانسون فوائد الكركم فوائد الزعتر قصص جحا تعريف الحب علامات الحمل

aminos lahragui said...



thanks so much i like very so much your post
حلى الاوريو الفطر الهندي صور تورته حلى قهوه طريقة عمل السينابون طريقة عمل بلح الشام بيتزا هت كيكة الزبادي حلا سهل
صور كيك عجينة العشر دقائق