By Bob Hockett
I’ve been planning to add my two or three cents’ worth of reflections on the current ‘health care reform’ controversies for a while now. I am delighted at last to be in effect forced to do so, via the assurances I made to my DoL friends last week that I’d be happy to try to help with the attempt to fill in here while Sherry and Mike are away. (Yah, I know – ‘“please, please, please,” in the words of the immortal James Brown – – hurry back!’ you are already crying out to the ColbDorfs.) And I am all the more delighted because, with reconciliation of the House and – one hopes, soon to be passed – Senate bills still ahead, there is still time to be prospectively rather than at best retrospectively relevant.
Had I managed to post earlier as I’d intended, I would have emphasized what I’ve thought – and still think – to be the most important insufficiently noticed aspect of the current ‘health care reform’ effort. That is the fact that we are currently engaged less in a ‘health care reform’ debate than in a ‘health insurance reform’ debate. And this is important because, as I elaborate in this article – – coming out in the economic policy journal Challenge, health insurance bears certain ‘natural monopoly’ characteristics that render much that might seem mysterious about recent proposals and debates more intelligible. In particular, they go a long way toward explaining (a) why it is that most states’ insurance markets are dominated by one or two health insurers, (b) why, relatedly, it is that the US’s peer nations in the OECD have long since treated health insurance (if not health care itself) as a social insurance problem on a par with retirement and unemployment insurance (if not public utilities), and (c) why, again relatedly, a ‘public option’ or Medicare extension, not to mention a repeal of the McCarran-Ferguson anti-trust law exemption enjoyed by US health insurers, would be so desirable as fall-backs in the absence of a full-bore ‘single payer’ or ‘single provider’ system of the sort maintained by all of our developed peer nations.
But I did not manage to post earlier as I’d intended. And while discussing the insurance-theoretic aspects of the current ‘health care reform’ debate still might be helpful in explaining the desirability of what remains of the Senate bill after the ravages wrought by Senators Lieberman and Nelson, I think that more value can be added now by addressing what looks apt to become more salient when the House and Senate turn to reconciling their health care reform bills. That is the matter of how the bills affect the delicately balanced regimes of abortion rights and abortion insurance in the US – a subject that strikes me as having generated rather more heat than light in the past month or so.
Now there is of course an awful lot that one could say about this subject, and saying either too much or too little runs the risk of adding much more to the heat than to the light. What I’d like to do, then, is limit myself here to one particularly charged issue that has come up already and is apt to come up again during the reconciliation process – the issue of abortion-neutrality. In a later post, I shall perhaps address a related but distinct issue – namely, that of what method of assessment ‘pro-lifers’ and ‘pro-choicers’ should employ in deciding whether to support or oppose legislation that they would tend unequivocally to favor were it not for what they view as its objectionable effects upon the abortion rights or abortion insurance regimes.
On then to abortion-neutrality. As most DoL readers will know, it has been viewed as a desideratum by most who acknowledge the need of greater health insurance accessibility and affordability – be they ‘pro-life’ or ‘pro-choice’ (I shall use the parties’ own preferred names for themselves) – that where abortion and its funding are concerned the status quo ante should be maintained as nearly as possible. That way the two sides can ‘agree to keep disagreeing’ on what they’ve long disagreed about, without this still intractable disagreement’s preventing their pushing forward on a distinct front about which they agree. The hope, then, is to ‘bracket’ abortion so as to avoid an agreed-to-be-needed reform’s being held hostage to a separate question on which no unanimously accepted resolution is yet in sight.
Now this (to my mind, altogether sensible) desideratum of abortion-neutrality raises at least two sub-desiderata: Pro-lifers, for their part, do not want to see any change that might tip the delicate balance thought to have been struck by the Hyde Amendment many years back, such as might result in federal moneys’ going toward the funding of abortion or treatments incidental thereto. Pro-choicers, for their part, do not want to see any change that might render abortion and related treatments less available, more stigmatized, or otherwise unduly burdened after legislation than before legislation. So we must navigate, if I might put it this way, through the Scylla and Charybdis that are Hyde and Casey.
The question raised by the abortion-neutrality desideratum, of course, is first whether the desideratum can be met, and second whether, if not, one can at least manage to err so minimally as to render the resultant legislation nevertheless acceptable to all. The later post that I said above I’ll perhaps offer later will be addressed to that second question. Here I address only the first. Thus far the foci of attempts to address this question have been the Stupak amendment to the House bill, and this past weekend’s Nelson-wrought change to the Senate bill.
With respect to the Stupak amendment, there seems now to be a broad consensus among many pro-lifers (at least the honest ones) and pro-choicers alike that it quite possibly violates the neutrality condition. The principal reason appears to be that, in restricting public assistance solely to those who purchase comprehensive health insurance policies not covering abortion, a Stupak-including bill will yield one of two unacceptable results: Either nobody will receive public assistance, because all comprehensive health insurance policies cover abortion; or abortion will become less available, because many or all firms will simply continue offering the same policies as before save without covering abortion.
A predicate assumption here – sometimes stated, sometimes not – is of course that insurance companies, owing to accounting costs, will not offer parallel comprehensive policies respectively covering and not covering abortion. I must admit to some uncertainty about the likelihood of the predicate assumption’s being vindicated or otherwise (it’s not clear to me whether all or most insurers would in fact go all or nothing), but as it happens I shall not have to address it. For I am going to propose what seems to me an obvious solution to this problem, if problem it is, in a moment – after considering the Senate’s Nelsononian alternative to the House’s Stupak Amendment.
With respect to the Nelsonian method of putatively assuring abortion-neutrality in the Senate bill, there seems to be greater uncertainty as to its likely effects than there is in the case of Stupak. Pro-lifers assert that the ‘one plan, two cheques’ regime contemplated by the measure is nothing but an ‘accounting gimmick,’ since it does not prohibit recipients of federal subsidies from availing themselves of the ‘abortion portion’ of insurance plans to which their second cheques go. In consequence, the argument proceeds, the spirit of the Hyde Amendment will be violated and for the first time, federal funds will be used for the financing of abortions. Meanwhile, pro-choicers object that the seemingly gratuitous transactions costs and stigmatization introduced by the Nelson-wrought change to the Senate bill constitute Casey-offensive undue burdens placed upon women who seek abortions. More seriously, they argue, the opt-out from federal subsidies that the Nelson measure affords states that object to possible expenditures by recipients on abortion-covering plans effectively gives states the power as it were to ‘go Stupak’ themselves. So Nelson amounts to a sort of ‘federalist Stupak.’
Now, what to make of these arguments as we go forward? Should we all just ‘grit our teeth’ and go the Nelson route, as some now are reporting that the House is readying itself to do? Well, if that’s the best we can do, maybe. But possibly we can do better – by both pro-life and pro-choice lights alike – with the most minimal of changes, such as will not risk scuttling reform altogether.
Here’s my suggestion: First note that oddly missing from the WWID (what would insurers do?) question that those on either side of the Stupak and Nelson debates assume answers to, as well as from these answers themselves, is any mention of the fact that we don’t have to speculate. We can mandate. Why not, then, simply require that all health insurers offer parallel plans? Abortion-covering plans – ‘A-plans’ – would cover abortion in the manner that most comprehensive plans do now. Non-abortion-covering plans – ‘NA-plans’ – would be, in all respects save abortion-coverage, identical. Then the final House-Senate reconciled bill can restrict subsidies to the purchase of NA-plans, and abortion-neutrality would seem thereby to be maintained. No new burden raised before those seeking abortion or its coverage, and no change to the Hyde regime governing federal funding of abortion.
This proposed solution would of course result in some additional (but surely de minimis, no?) accounting costs to be faced by the insurers. But that seems apt to be a pittance in comparison to the great boon that the ‘health care reform’ legislation, alas, as it’s now shaping up, is conferring upon them. (Had a look at the share price performances of the majors ever since Senator Lieberman’s bombshell of last week?) More importantly, it would place the burden of adjustment on the insurers, which are not hurting, rather than on would-be insureds, who either are hurting already or will be hurting if abortion-neutral health reform legislation is not crafted.
Another problem with this proposed solution might be that it appears, perhaps perversely in the eyes of pro-lifers, to require something never required before – namely, that private insurers offer abortion-covering health plans. But this appearance is surely no more than the epiphenomenal by-product of a misleading ‘framing effect.’ For it is anything but clear, on reflection, that ‘requiring’ something that is already done anyway amounts to anything more than a prohibition from withdrawing, in response to legislation that pro-lifers themselves by hypothesis approve, something long hitherto offered. For again, all that this requirement would do is ensure that that possible result feared by Stupak-opponents – the withdrawal of insurance coverage for abortion by private firms responding to health reform legislation – not materialize. That seems an entirely innocent result if and insofar as it is the only means of assuring bona fide abortion-neutrality in the health reform legislation.
One final perceived obstacle to my proposed solution to the neutrality problem is that it would amount to a federal requirement placed upon health insurers, while the McCarran-Ferguson regime under which we continue to live reserves the power to regulate insurance to the states. This doesn’t seem a serious obstacle, however. For one thing, the change I propose, coming later in time, would presumably amount simply to an implicit partial-repeal of McCarran-Ferguson, rather as sundry ERISA provisions already do. For another thing, as I’ve argued elsewhere and will continue to argue in future in another connection – that of financial regulation – it is high time we repealed McCarran-Ferguson in any event. But more of that on another day.
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
6 comments:
Sadly, you over-estimate the honesty of the 'anti-choice' part of the debate -- I will not use their self-chosen name -- by several orders of magnitude. The leaders -- and that large proportion of their folowers who have neither the time, tools, nor the inclination to test their statements against the facts -- have no desire for a compromise more sensible than the Nelson/Casey one. In fact, they reject this as -- quoting simply from the last week, as reported by PFAW's "Right Wing Watch" (Sorry for not blockquoting, but Blogger does not accept it, so I am alternating bold, italics, and plain type)
"Senators Ben Nelson and Robert Casey gave mere lip service to protecting the most innocent among us by placing their stamp of approval on government funding for abortion coverage in direct conflict with longstanding policy. (Tony Perkins)
We reject and renounce Sen. Reid's bill being pushed through the Senate, including Sen. Casey's and Sen. Nelson's compromised amendments.(Lou Engle)
The Senate bill forces the American people to conspire with the federal government in murdering innocent children. This is morally unacceptable.(Mat Staver)
We vehemently and unequivocally oppose any and all healthcare legislation that funds abortion directly or indirectly, explicitly or implicitly without exception. Abortion is not health care. We oppose any and all legislation, language or compromise that surrenders this core value on the altar of political expediency.(Samuel Rodriguez)
Today Ben Nelson let down Nebraska and he let down Americans who oppose government-funded elective abortion. It's a tragedy that Senator Nelson has paved the way for legislation that departs from the status quo. If this bill passes, for the first time, federally funded and managed health care plans will cover elective abortions. Pro-life Americans in Nebraska and other states that choose to 'opt-out' of abortion coverage will still be forced to foot the bill for abortions in California and New York.(Susan B. Anthony List President Marjorie Dannenfelser)
“This compromise offers no real protection for human life and does nothing to keep federal health care funds from being used for abortion,” said Jay Sekulow, Chief Counsel of the ACLJ. “The fact is that the Senate bill specifically authorizes federal funds to be used for abortions. The so-called 'protections' in the compromise simply require that the federal subsidies and premium dollars that are collected for these services be kept separate from other federal funds. The end result provides no restrictions on abortions, but simply sets up what can only be described as a scheme that allows for federal funding of abortions, which directly violates long-standing federal law under the Hyde Amendment.”
Senator Ben Nelson appears to have overlooked some realities. The option for states to opt out of abortion coverage is illusory. The federal government will be subsidizing elective abortions, a federal agency will be managing abortion coverage, and individuals (even those in Nebraska) will be paying for abortions through an accounting scheme. Under current federal law and programs, federal funds may not be used for any part of a plan that covers elective abortions. The human right not to be forced to be an accomplice to an evil act, in this case the deliberate murder of innocent babies, is a basic decency that the government should not force individuals or entities to violate.
"This scheme will increase abortions, causing more women to suffer the health and psychological complications that come with this act. How significant that it comes during the Christmas season. Jesus Christ's birth to an unwed teenager prompted a government official (Herod) to use government resources to murder innocent babies.(Wendy Wright, CWA)
-------
These comments, all from this week, show how likely a compromise as sensible as yours would be to be accepted.
Many thanks, Mr. Benton,
I'm so very happy that you find the proposed compromise sensible. For my part, I share your pessimism about the good faith of many of those in the camp you here mention. I will say, however, that I know a number of 'pro-lifers' who, believe it or not, really are outraged by the non-neutrality and apparent opportunism of the Stupak folk and even of some of the Nelson folk. I fear that you might well be right about the majority in this camp, but, hopelessly Quixotic optimist that I am, I find myself hoping there might at least be more of the good faith 'pro-life neutrals' than the few whom I'm privileged to know.
Thanks again, and happy holidays!
Bob
Some essential expenses and advantages may not be agreeable to http://www.mmomesos.com/ to quantitative statistic. For example, some of the pro-gun briefs in Heller suggested that extensive gun possession is a protect against despotism because it preserves the choice of efficient rebel (thereby detering the would-be despot). Although some annecdotal proof was introduced in assistance (no despotism has ever permitted extensive personal gun ownership), it's not obvious how the advantage to community (if any) from this impact could be quantified.
An important tricks of success with info programs is meeting the requirements of your audience. Consider what your audience desires to know, a beachside lounge chair, precisely how! Next, take an inventory of product ideas. As an example, a photographer could write its own number of how to take flattering pictures, a pet fanatic could write a written report about first-aid for pets or perhaps gardener could write a guide on plant care from the wintertime.
mulberry bags
mulberry bayswater
mulberry bags sale
mulberry uk sale
Wish you and your family would enjoy the amazing life. At the same time, Diabloiiigold will always offer the affordable and fast support for every client. 24/7 live time will help you fix problems with best quality. To demonstrate our appreciation, we have ready benefits action for our new clients. Absolutely, we will offer away more love to our trustworthy clients.
Buy WOW Gold RS Gold Buy Diablo 3 Gold
桃園徵信公司
雲林徵信公司
徵信社公會
徵信社尋人
徵信社工作
商業間諜
抓姦委託調查
外遇徵信社
結婚週年
第三者背景
夫妻
外遇抓姦
澎湖徵信社
豪門婚姻
貴婦
養男人
大陸徵信社
夫妻財產
澳門徵信社
淫婦
婚變
北京徵信
外遇二奶
北京徵信社
婚姻暴力
徵信達人狗仔網
Post a Comment